US retail sales…Is the Sun really shining again?

Retail sales takeaways:

  • In rebound mode, but nothing as yet to suggest trend of slowing growth cycles has been broken.
  • Motor Vehicle and Parts sales, a key driver of sales growth heretofore, looks to have slipped to a much lower gear: less consumer credit growth fuelling demand?
  • Retail sales adjusted for CPI ex shelter and adjusted for population growth only just bubbling up around pre crisis levels.
  • Seasonality: some questions over the extent to which seasonality is impacting the data.
  • Inventory to retail sales growth at historically high levels: economy exposed to heightened short term risks to spending.
  • CPI ex shelter, flatlining post 2012.
  • Boundaries to retail sales growth: consumer credit to disposable income ratios, long term income growth declines, peak personal consumption expenditures and continuation of weak profile post late 1990s: longer term dynamics at play.

Continue reading

Debt and wealth in a monetary system, part 2: discounted valuation issues in a declining frame with inequalities.

We are presently building up conflicts within the asset price frame:

  • Conflicts between asset values and GDP flows and their growth rates;
  • Between asset prices and return expectations;
  • Between human capital values and the distribution of those values and their impact on the overall wealth equation with respect to future consumption risks as well as asset pricing via increased asset focus of flows due to distribution dynamics;
  • Within portfolio structure and relative to the liquidity and capital security dynamics of liability streams. 

All of this tied to the relationship between frame transitions, emergent properties and structural imbalances and unconventional monetary policy focused overly on asset price support.

Continue reading

Are debt and wealth really two separate forces in a monetary system? Part 1

I write with reference to a discussion in a recent Bloomberg View article, We’re Still Not Sure What Causes Big Recessions.

Debt/broad money supply is a key foundation of asset and human capital values and their supporting GDP flows.  Because of this, wealth and debt effects (new loans create deposits) on GDP/income flows should not be considered as separate forces. 

Debt in its money supply origination (bank deposits) is a foundation of both GDP flows and asset values and it is when debt, and specifically in the form defined, increases relative to GDP/national income flows that we should pay attention.  And we need to pay attention to all flows, not just income flows on risky assets, for example corporate profits which can squeeze out returns on both fixed interest and human capital during periods of enforced low interest rate policy.

Money leverages many activities, and asset values are always to a certain extent in a form of a bubble, but excess leverage, especially during periods where we have structural imbalances and frame transitions creates instability and risks to the financial system. 

Frame transitions that we need to watch out for with respect to excess asset focused money supply growth are where drivers of GDP growth are in decline (labour and population demographics, productivity and global transitions impacting the same) requiring lower levels of capital or growth rates of capital accumulation resulting in increasing levels of capital depreciation.  In this context monetary frame dynamics should also be contracting or slowing.  Frame transitions can be accentuated by increasing income and wealth inequality, something that may also be an emergent property of economic systems during frame transitions.   This can also leverage asset prices to prospective GDP flows.

Continue reading

Perspectives on US New Manufacturing Order data:

Key takeaways:

  • The frame should dominate analysis of new order fundamentals: long term weakness dominates.
  • The new order bounce back in March/April was led by the transportation sector (MVPs in particular), but the bounce back should be set against the depth of the declines.
  • Outside transportation the trend is very weak.
  • Consumer durable goods orders on a smoothed 6 monthly basis have weakened noticeably since the start of the year.

Commentators are increasingly concerned about the risk of a recession in the US Economy.  Recessions are typically short term step backs/retracements within expanding frames whereas we are in a rather complicated contracting one the one hand (developed economies) and transitioning frame (developing economies moving from investment dependence to consumption/service sector dependence) on the other characterised by excessive debt levels, unconventional monetary policy and increasing income inequality to name but a few fundamental issues. 

So let us look at US manufacturing new order data, at first in terms of the frame, which bounced back on a monthly basis in April:

The frame

We can see from the following chart that annualised real growth rates over rolling 10 year time frames (using new order data adjusted for PPI and smoothed) have been heading downwards since the start of the decade.  The real annualised rate of growth over rolling 10 year time frames shows that the current cycle is much weaker than the pre 2008 cycle.

image

We can see the step down in growth more easily if we just view the high water mark dynamics (which ignores the current index level if it remains below the HWM).

image

In reality given the declines in flows since 2014, new orders for manufacturing adjusted for the PPI stand below levels reached at the end of the 1990s, and yet, here we are all worried about the risk of recession when the risk of something far greater has already occurred.  Tied into the frame is the key dynamic of global rebalancing: cheap labour in emerging/developing economies had offshored a significant amount of manufacturing output from the late 1990s onwards (the weak order data partly reflects this) and the expected maturing of developing economies consumers and rising wage costs was anticipated by many to create a rebalancing of global economies.  This is presently at risk a) due to the time frame of transition being longer than many expect and b) given that technology is driving out labour in key industries.

And in the next chart we see nominal annualised rates for new orders over rolling 10 year time frames: clearly the structure and balance and dynamics of the US economy and the attendant global economic dynamics are unable to support the type of growth the economy had experienced in post WWII years.  The primary issue we are facing today is not one of a prospective recession but of a weakening frame:

image

Continue reading

US incomes…peaked or just about to surge?

If we look at real disposable personal income growth from the latest BEA data update we see what might appear to be, on the surface, a robust recovery:

image

Quarterly data shows similar traction:

image

But real data has benefited from falling energy prices and nominal flows are not as strong, in fact if we focus on nominal flows we are in the midst of a clear downward movement:

Continue reading

US ISM Manufacturing PMI…supplier deliveries, a true or false signal?

The US ISM Manufacturing PMI ticked up marginally today indicating slightly stronger manufacturing activity.  The change was small from 50.8 to 51.3.   While output and new order indicators fell, employment remained the same and inventories declined slightly, supplier deliveries slowed at the fastest pace for some time.  The month on month change in supplier deliveries was 10.2%, only bettered on 5 occasions over the last 35 years.  

But supplier deliveries tend to lag new orders and we also know that new manufacturing orders fell significantly in late 2015 and have since bounced back (data in the chart below is to March 2016). 

image

The bounce in supplier deliveries look to be related to the bounce back in PMI new order indicator starting in late 2015 and we can see this lag here:

image

The bounce in new order data was also the strongest since the recession ended and is usually associated with cyclical turning points. 

image

But, with the continued slowdown in global manufacturing PMIs and weakness in the ISM’s other PMI components as well as weakness in readings from Markit’s own indicator I would not be too upbeat about any possible signal.  We appear to be stuck in a slowing growth trend market by downs and gradually weakening ups!

And from Markit’s own PMI release:

“The survey data indicate that factory output fell in May at its fastest rate since 2009, suggesting that manufacturing is acting as a severe drag on the Page 2 of 3 © Markit economy in the second quarter. Payroll numbers are under pressure as factories worry about slower order book growth, in part linked to falling export demand but also as a result of growing uncertainty surrounding the presidential election

CPB World Trade Monitor and Flash PMIs

We are clearly in a period of weak global growth as shown by the 6 monthly rates of change in export volumes.  What makes the current weakness of note is that it is the second such decline in the last year and the most pronounced outside of 2001 and 2008/2009:

image

image

And a closer look:

image

If we look at smoothed data which adjusts for monthly extremes we find further confirmation of weakness both at the annual and the six monthly:

image

And a closer look at the annual rate:

image

We can also look at the data from a high water mark perspective:

image

Again at both the monthly and six monthly data we see significant weakness from early 2015 followed by a late year recovery, followed by further weakness.

But the CPB World Trade Monitor is always a couple of months behind which is why current flash PMI data from the various Markit Surveys suggests that weakness has continued across global markets:

Markit Flash US Manufacturing PMI :crept closer to stagnation in May….overall business conditions…weakest since the current upturn started in October 2009….renewed fall in production…softer new order growth…further cuts to stocks of inputs….U.S. manufacturers signalled the first reduction in output since September 2009 in May….uncertainty…caused clients to delay spending decisions…reduced foreign client demand had underpinned slower growth in overall new orders…outstanding work at U.S. manufacturers falling for the fourth successive month in May….

Markit Flash Eurozone PMI – rate manufacturing output growth…second-weakest since February 2015. Growth of new orders received by factories also eased. Producers reported that domestic market conditions remained tough and softer international trade flows led to the smallest rise in new export business for 16 months.

Nikkei Flash Japan Manufacturing PMI™ – “Manufacturing conditions deteriorated at a faster rate mid-way through the second quarter of 2016…Both production and new orders declined sharply and at the quickest rates in 25 and 41 months respectively….a marked contraction in foreign demand, which saw the sharpest fall in over three years….

Thoughts on revisions to US manufacturing new order data

US durable goods order data out yesterday suggested a strong rebound in new orders in April led principally by transportation orders.  But I am not going to talk about the new data (at least until I get the full manufacturing new order data set due shortly), I want to talk about the difference between the new and the old order data:

image

Data to March 2016 had been revised down by some 2% for manufacturing orders and the rate of revision was similar for both durable and non durable goods.

However the wider picture shows that transportation, in particular motor vehicles and parts orders showed significant upward revisions:

image

On the other side of the variance we see non defence capital goods excluding aircraft, computers and electronic goods and primary metals heavily negatively revised:

image

The picture confirms the relative strength we have seen in auto led consumer credit growth on the one hand and weakness in exports and capital expenditure on the other.

A few thoughts on “Rise of the Robots”, risks to global rebalancing and much more

Foxconn replaces ’60,000 factory workers with robots’” was a recent headline in a BBC news report, and of course many other stories.

The global rebalancing story goes as follows: developed economies offshore production of goods in cheap labour emerging markets with strong growth prospects, benefiting from cheaper labour and also entrance into consumer markets with vast potential.  Developed economies experience declines in wage growth as manufacturing declines and service sector expands in relative terms, interest rates are lowered and consumer credit growth stimulated.   Lower cost goods and low interest rates cushion the impact of lower wage growth but the economy moves out of balance, towards consumption and debt (increasingly asset focussed) and away from production and investment.  

Ultimately this story depended on developing markets maturing their own consumer stories and wage growth/currencies rising to erase or at least obfuscate wage price differentials.  This rebalancing of developing economies to consumption and away from manufacturing/investment would have created demand for goods, services and expertise of developed economies, rebalancing GDP away from consumption and towards production and investment, raising wages and reducing dependence on credit for consumption with interest rates slowly re-ascending.

The story about Foxxconn factory workers being replaced with robots takes away important marginal flows from the rebalancing equation and reemphasises emergent income distribution inequalities: less income to labour, more to capital; reduced consumer expenditure growth to rebalance growth in developing/developed areas; greater stress on high debt levels accumulated in both areas, debt levels used to finance consumption in one and infrastructure and manufacturing in the other.  And of course, all the attendant asset price issues that have arisen as a result of low interest, financial shocks, asset price support and other unconventional monetary policy actions.

Technology is a good thing and we should always be striving to produce more efficiently and effectively and part of the move to robots in these developing markets is the reallocation of labour capital across the broader economy and the need to produce ever more goods for growing demand in many of these vast economies. 

But the separation of income flows, or at least higher growth higher value income flows to labour, is a disconcerting one and especially so given the ongoing deceleration of global economic growth and asset price divergence.  This not only accentuates the trend towards increasing income inequality and therefore damages the eco system’s ability to regenerate demand (and support asset prices), increasing reliance on loan growth (and hence debt support), but it also risks prevent a more rigorous and necessary rebalancing of growth between developing and developed that would have re-established the balance of power between labour capital and financial capital that would be necessary to keep the eco system’s flows at regenerative levels. 

Within the capitalist system there are numerous subtleties.   Human beings need a reason for being and the economic dreams of home ownership, durable goods consumption and various other lifestyle goals are gradually being hammered away and left to an increasingly small percentage of the population.   The objective of a capitalist system should be productive efficiency on the one hand and the regeneration of the model’s ability to support its asset, human and of course natural frame.   Technology has not historically been a blight on humanity, but that has been because of various forces that have coincidentally expanded the frontier of consumption and production capabilities.   

Productive efficiency is only one side of the equation and it requires balancing forces on the other to maintain a healthy “equilibrium” of sorts between all factors of production.   Talk of helicopter money, the drive for increasingly perverse unconventional monetary policy all strongly suggest that the equation that drives the eco system is out of balance.

Some obscure perspectives on Canadian Household expenditure

An economy is an asset that produces flows of consumption and investment expenditure.  In a growing economy you would expect these flows to grow.  Household consumption expenditure, while growing larger every year, has ceased to increase at a faster rate year on year for some time:

image

If we exclude imputed rent paid by households (money not actually spent) and money spent on games of chance (excluded here for the benefit of the analysis to follow), annual year on year (Q on Q basis) shows data as of Q4 2015 below growth in flows reached in the late 1980s:

image

Why have I deducted games of chance from expenditure?  Well the main reason is I believe that increased expenditure on games of chance is more a sign of consumer stress than consumer health:

image

Imputed rent, also a proxy for housing affordability, as a % of household expenditure has increased to close to 16% while expenditure on recreation and culture ex games of chance has fallen steadily since its peak in 1999.

The divergence can be better seen in the following chart showing annual Q on Q increases in these expenditures:

image

Canada: some niggles in savings rate data..

As of Q4 2015 the household savings rate was some 4%, down from 15% as of the early 1990s:

image

But the data hides a starker reality: disposable income less household expenditure in Q4 2015 left a savings rate of 0.5%.  The 4% savings rate is actually made up for the most part of a pension adjustment, a factor which has held relatively stable.  Not much room here for increasing expenditure.

image

Indeed we see a big drop in savings ex pension adjustment from 1993 onwards, matched by a large increase in consumer credit and a further deeper plunge from 2002 to 2008, matched again by consumer credit.   I cannot find stat data from Stats Canada or the Bank of Canada on HELOCs which would provide further information on influences on household expenditure (secured home equity lines of credit being far cheaper than unsecured consumer credit) but the consumer credit data seems to coincide quite well with the drop in savings rates:

image

Household and NPO debt relative to GDP continues to rise:

image

Canadian Retail Sales: slowing and heavily dependent on Autos

Retail sales fell 1% in cash terms in March on February and by 1.3% in volume terms.  Over the year volume (real) retail sales grew 1.77% and by cash (nominal) 3.17%.

In real terms real volume based retail sales look to be in a declining growth trend (note the smoothed data line) of lower highs and lower lows:

image

Across Canada we see weakness in Alberta and relative strength in Ontario over the year in nominal terms:

image

But monthly rates of change are slowing considerably from a peak in mid 2015:

image

If we just focus on annual data for Canada we see a very strong out of trend upward move

image

But this is primarily from motor vehicles and parts sales:

image

If we take away motor vehicles and parts and we see a flat retail sales picture (index January 2014 100):

image

The disparity between retail sales and retail sales ex motor vehicle and parts sales has not been this big for years:

image

But the trend is bigger if we just compare MVP sales to retail sales ex MVP:image

We can see this disparity below: the largest since the early 1990s, itself a rebound from the recently ended recession, so the current strength is significant.image

We can see that motor vehicle and parts sales has contributed close to 60% of retail sales over the last three ears:

image

So how does motor vehicle and part sales compare with wage growth?  If we look at cumulative data, in this case annualised rates of change over rolling 5 year periods, we see that motor vehicle and parts sales have well exceeded increases in hourly wage growth:

image

US Employment data, key points and filler!

Unlike retail sales, industrial production, new orders or a number of other economic data, the employment report comes with a lot of extra filler.  You need to dig down into the ingredients to figure what is and what is not good.  On the surface we have seen a recent deceleration, but nothing which looks out of the ordinary post 2009.

image

But what do we see when we dig? 

  • Productivity growth at post war lows!  Employment data is producing less and less and becoming in GDP, asset price support and income growth terms, increasingly diluted.
  • Health care and social assistance has been key to recent employment growth but the growth rate is falling off.  Looking after an aging society may not produce the growth needed to sustain the liabilities attached to the economic frame.  Indeed, many of these liabilities may not be adequately accounted for within asset valuations.
  • If we exclude health care and social assistance from employment date, employment levels only returned to growth on an annual basis in October 2014, making the current employment growth cycle a short one to date.
  • Add food service and drinking places employment (to health care and social assistance) and we have the sum total of jobs created since the recession started.  But even food services and drinking places employment growth has shown a recent declining trend.   Again, the income/productivity dynamics of this type of employment is unsupportive of the current asset/liability frame.
  • Retail trade employment growth was especially strong during the latter part of 2015 (dominated by motor vehicles and parts dealers), although we have seen weakening of late.  Watch out for MVP employment (which means an eye on consumer credit) and buildings and materials (which means an eye on construction).  There has been weakness on the retail side that is obscured by recent April data
  • The weakness in the goods producing industries, construction excepted, and trade and transport is noteworthy in the light of weakness in output, new orders and exports.  These are all key industries in terms of the economy’s ability to provide generate long term GDP, income and productivity growth.   Manufacturing and trade are important cogs in the economic machine.
  • The one relatively strong point in the data remains the professional and technical sub sector of professional services.  Relative to service sector (and hence all employment) it has continued to rise in importance, but the growth rate of this dynamic has slowed in the current cycle.  This may not be a positive for income flows if it represents a movement towards rationalisation of processes (reduced employment at the front end and a small increase at the operational core), reflective of cost reduction and other operational rationalisation.
  • Long term dynamics  – employment growth rates/part time versus full time/self employment versus employed – are all weakening or stuck in a post recession rut.  A lot of recent employment gains look like they are due to a rise in part time employment (which may be a positive if it signals increasing willingness to hire) so growth fundamentals are still very weak and possibly weakening. 

What makes employment growth and the make up of employment growth so important is that it impacts productivity and earnings growth, two key factors that require vigour if we are to accommodate high debt levels and high asset prices.  Other relevant relationships include capital investment (historically weak), income inequality and a slowdown in population growth as well as a shift in its demographics.   Finally, with weak global trade dynamics we have considerable pressure on areas of the economy that have traditionally been important to productivity and earnings growth.  

There is nothing wrong in a declining population and declining growth rates of employment as long as the relationship between asset values (debt/equity) and consumption/investment dynamics are in keeping.   I very much doubt whether it is and this is why employment growth today is a much more important indicator of financial health than it is fundamental economic health.  There are so many straws in the wind!

And the graphics:

Continue reading

US retail sales….not so pretty a picture

Some concerns with the April data:

  • April is seasonally a weak month and any transfer of consumption capacity to it would skew the monthly data in favour of a higher seasonally adjusted change.
  • It is not the rebound in the data that is important but the strength of the trend.  The pattern over the last 3 years is for a weakening in the strength of the rebound and retail sales growth.
  • Inventories are high relative to sales but they have likely never been higher once we factor in the growth rate of inventories relative to sales.

And the supporting graphics:

image

Seasonally adjusted retail sales grew at the fastest rate for some time.  Eye popping almost! But April is typically a weak month and we have had relative weakness during Q1 2016.  

The following chart shows the actual, unadjusted, expenditure on a monthly basis for the above seasonally adjusted chart.  If consumption capacity had been transferred to April from prior months its adjusted impact would have been skewed.

image

More importantly is whether the rebound in adjusted consumption represents a continuation of a weakening trend or not?  This is the real question!

image

Also, retail inventories relative to sales remain at relatively high levels:

image

The highest level since 2004/2005.  However, once we realise that 2004/2005 inventory levels accompanied higher retail sales growth relative to inventory growth we can see that the inventory/sales dynamic is weaker still.

image

Presentation to the Expert Committee To Consider Financial Advisory And Financial Planning Policy Alternatives on Behalf of SIPA

Please note the following small presentation I provided with respect to the above on behalf of the Small Investor Protection Association on 3 May in Toronto.

———

The Small Investor Protection Association fully supports recognising the importance of professionalism in financial planning. 

Financial planning is an important component of a wealth management universe focused on the processes and frameworks that underpin the efficient planning, construction and management of personal financial assets and their liabilities over time.  

Wealth management is a complex area and those firms and individuals providing advice within it have considerable discretion over the processes that plan, structure, manage, educate and communicate.  We believe that this discretion, the complexity of the processes and the asymmetry of knowledge and experience place the professional advisor and the firm in a position of great responsibility.  SIPA believes that this places fiduciary duties, accountabilities and responsibilities on advisors for the processes that plan, structure, manage and communicate outcomes irrespective of whether the service’s nomenclature is discretionary or advisory and irrespective of title.   

Existing regulation, at the advisory level, needs to widen its remit to those services’ processes that underpin wealth management outcomes and away from a predisposition with the transaction.

It fully supports raising the standards and the integrity of service processes involved in the planning the construction and management of financial needs service processes while deemphasising the role of the transaction in process, regulation and remuneration.

The problems we see in the delivery, quality and accountability of service outcomes lie with a system that rewards the transaction and that overly focuses on the transaction in its service processes.  The focus on the transaction de-emphasises the importance of construction, planning and management in advice based service processes and constrains the development of services that put the client’s best interests first and foremost in the process.  The current system does not operate wholly in the best interests of the investor, whether this is at the advisor, firm or regulatory level.  

As the CFA institute and the Canadian Advocacy Council for Canadian CFA Institute Societies both point out, “the current regulatory scheme is incomplete”. 

SIPA is concerned over the division amongst Canadian regulators as to the merits of introducing best interest standards and the removal of commissions.  It is also concerned that even the proposed statutory best interest standard may itself be diminished by industry interests and calls on Canada’s democratically elected legislatures to become directly involved in the modernisation of Canada’s regulatory system. It believes that advisors’ responsibilities and duties with respect to advice, processes and communications are indeed fiduciary ones. 

And from SIPA’s own submission on the subject:

“This illusion fed to the general public is unfair. It results in many personal tragedies when hard working people lose their lifetime savings quite often late in life when they do not have the time to recover. It creates desperate life-altering events that result in health issues, loss of hope and faith, disruption of families and sometimes victims taking their own life.”

We live in a trusting society. Canadians believe they can trust professionals that are regulated like doctors, lawyers and other professionals. Yes, they trust their “Financial Advisors” because they believe they are regulated professionals. They are not aware they are simply sales persons without responsibility to look after clients’ best interests; they do not feel a need to study medicine or a need to study finance and investments. They are busy with careers and family.

A small investor exclaims and asks “why are regulators not collecting fines for serious violations of securities regulations?”!

This is a brief post on a very important and highly complex issue that cannot be done justice in the space provided.  There are many issues today, in Canada’s financial services industry, where funding for independent research of issues impacting consumers would be of tremendous value to the continuing debate over standards and regulation

Canada’s Small Investor Protection Association (a small non profit organisation that serves as a voice and resource for Canadian investors who have been subjected to financial abuse and/or bad advice by the financial services industry) recently released a report by one of its members on unpaid fines levied by regulators on industry participants but which have not yet been collected.  The report has been discussed in numerous articles, the most detailed of which is found in a piece written by Yvonne Colbert of CBC news.

Continue reading

US Q1 GDP..big picture concerns conflate with shorter term weakness!

The big picture is the risk that growth may well have peaked in the current cycle:

image

And personal consumption expenditure flows (population adjusted) have arced in a worrying sign of secular decline for some time:

image

GDP growth less private employment growth has been negative since Q4 2010, one of the very few such periods in the post war period and the weakest to date and symptomatic of weak productivity and wage growth:

image

image

Preliminary US GDP grew by a real $22bn in the first quarter.  Given that we are unlikely to see the weather related bounce back in growth that we saw last year, we are left wondering where growth is going to come from in the second and third quarters, especially if global trade fundamentals remain weak.

Continue reading

The slowdown continues

Manufacturing is a central cog in the growth frame and declining growth rates should be a cause for concern.  Today’s Markit flash PMI’s for the US, Japan and Europe showed continued deterioration in manufacturing fundamentals:

US Manufacturing– ““US factories reported their worst month for just over six-and-a-half years in April, dashing hopes that first quarter weakness will prove temporary. “Survey measures of output and order book backlogs are down to their lowest since the height of the global financial crisis, prompting employers to cut back on their hiring. “The survey data are broadly consistent with manufacturing output falling at an annualized rate of over 2% at the start of the second quarter, and factory employment dropping at a rate of 10,000 jobs per month.”

Japan Manufacturing – Manufacturing conditions in Japan worsened at a sharper rate in April. Both production and new orders declined markedly, with total new work contracting at the fastest rate in over three years. The sharp drop in total new work was underpinned by the fastest fall in international demand since December 2012, and following the two earthquakes on the island of Kyushu (one of Japan’s key manufacturing regions), the outlook of the goods-producing sector now looks especially uncertain.

Euro Zone Composite – ““The eurozone economy remains stuck in a slow growth rut in April, with the PMI once again signalling GDP growth of just 0.3% at the start of the second quarter, broadly in line with the meagre pace of expansion seen now for a full year. “A failure of business expectations to revive following the ECB’s announcement of more aggressive stimulus in March is a major disappointment and suggests that the modest pace of growth is unlikely to accelerate in coming months. “France continues to act as a major drag on the region, with goods exports slumping to the greatest extent for over three years. Germany and the rest of the region are enjoying more robust expansions by comparison, though growth rates slowed in April. “

The US data followed on the heels of weak industrial/manufacturing production for March and a weakening Chicago Fed National Activity index.

image

image

US manufacturing remains in a long term funk: the last time we had such weakness in the US was during the depression and the post war adjustment.

image

Monthly rates of change in manufacturing show weakness on both a monthly and smoothed trend basis:

image

Motor vehicle assemblies look to have peaked and supports recent weakening in retail sales;

image

image

imageimage

CPB World Trade Monitor Update

The recent CPB World Trade Monitor Update (to February): growth in world trade volumes despite a February rebound from a January decline, based on high water mark analysis, are showing significant weakness:

image_thumb[10]

World export growth based on smoothed 6 monthly data has shown significant weakening:

image_thumb[13]

Add in weak readings in the recent flash Markit Manufacturing PMIs for Japan, the US and Europe, the weak St Louis Fed GDP Now readings and slowdown in Q1 China growth, and we see little in the tea levels that would suggest any meaningful reversion in the above trend is underway.

Continue reading

Links

IMF Warns Debt Risk Growing From Big Firms in China, Other Emerging Markets, April, WSJ

In China, fully $1.3 trillion of corporate loans, or one-seventh of the total, are owed by companies whose profits don’t cover their interest payments, a problem that could trigger bank losses equal to 7% of gross domestic product if the issue isn’t addressed, the IMF said in a report on global financial stability.

Chinese Buyers Hungry for Canadian Homes With Inquiries Up 134%, April Bloomberg

China and India Have Different Answers for Their Debt Messes, April Bloomberg

Mounting debts could derail China plans to cut steel, coal glut, March, Reuters

China’s debt bubble threatens global economy March, Nikkei Asian Review

China’s debt explosion threatens financial stability Fitch warns, April, Telegraph

“Living standards fell in 2015, ONS figures show”, April, Guardian

National Accounts articles: Alternative measures of real households disposable Income and the saving ratio: March 2016

Shows a decline in household disposable income if we remove imputed rents, pension entitlement adjustments and other non cash adjustments used to define PDI and savings rates.   With respect to savings rates we see a different picture too:

chartimage

The U.S. Housing Affordability Crisis: How a Rent and Low-Income Problem is Becoming Everyone’s Problem, April, Zillow

Active Share: Key Insight or Flawed Measure? February, CFA Institute

Night Fasting: Not Eating For 13 Hours Or More Every Night May Reduce Risk Of Breast Cancer Recurrence, March, Medical Daily

Intermittent Fasting, March, Australian Spinal Research Foundation

US retail sales…update

It is a trend I have been following for some time….global growth is slowing down at a time in the cycle when you would usually expect to see inflation and supply bottlenecks.  If it were not for the very high levels of asset focussed money supply growth over the last few decades and the build up of debt and asset values (dependent on this growth), I would not be ringing any bells.  But the divergence between what asset values need growth to be and what growth is turning out to be is the problem.

US retail sales (I am still waiting for the CPI update which will allow for a better assessment of retail volumes) took a further hit in March:

image

image

image

The biggest contributor to the recent slide has been motor vehicles and parts sales.  This component has also been the biggest contributor to retail sales growth post the 2008/2009 recession and a large contributor to significant increases in consumer credit debt loads:

image

image

image

image

The inventory picture has also darkened with the longer term inventory to sales relationship showing an unusual divergence:

image

Last month’s analysis

http://blog.moneymanagedproperly.com/?p=5056

Bubbles….what are they and why can the Fed not see them?

In a previous post:

I commented on Janet Yellen’s putdown of suggestions of excess usually associated with the term “bubble” and graphically demonstrated that there existed a significant divergence between US economic/income growth and asset values (debt/equity) that would suggest a bubble of sizeable proportions existed. 

I also provided a link to a prior post on bubbles that mentioned per se that the very fact that asset values tended to discount the future, in a monetary system, meant that bubbles were in fact a de facto natural component of a monetary driven economic paradigm.  The key issue was the balance and the relationship between the two, itself a function of the nature and balance of fundamental economic relationships and their emergent properties.   A great many of my previous posts assert the existence of a perilous divergence and describes the many imbalances that have accentuated this imbalance and which have added to its instability.  

When we talk of bubbles in the same frame as bursting and collapse what we are talking about are unsustainable relationships that are being pushed to their extremes and beyond.   We are talking about divergence in the order of things, about structures whose natural relationships are being pushed so far out of alignment that minor shocks produce extreme outcomes..  This is where the statistician’s fat tail comes in and once we realise that we have an imbalance it is no longer a fat tail but a much higher probability outcome.

A bubble may burst in the sense that the growth of the energy in the system exceeds its structural ability to continue to expand at a rate consistent with the change in energy.   This could be seen as inflation in the economy or as inflation in an asset price as demand for that asset outstripped its value and the ability to supply that demand.  Bubbles in this context can lead to misallocation of resources as noted in a recent BIS report on this issue.  

A bubble can also deflate in the sense that the energy driving the fundamental drivers of growth in the system either no longer require the frame to expand at the same rate or, indeed, that the financial frame needs to scale backwards to accommodate the decline in system energy (this would be the case where demographics are slowing and are in decline and where productivity growth has slowed and also where distribution of income is impaired). 

If monetary and fiscal decision makers view the gear change in growth as a temporary aberration and attempt to force expansion of either/or both the fundamentals and the financial frame, when in fact the frame is naturally contracting (depreciating) or its growth rate slowing, then we risk divergence between the fundamental drivers of the system and the frame.  In other words the energy added to the system complicates the much needed adjustment of the  frame as stimulus temporarily expands both, and in the current case, expands the financial frame at a growth rate well in excess of the fundamentals whose own trajectory has been temporarily amended.

In other words where we have had slowing demographics, transitory economics and monetary stimulus as well as increasingly skewed distributions of national income.  We have had a de facto bubble developing and this has manifested itself in ever higher levels of debt and asset focussed money supply growth at the same time as productivity/demographic/CAPEX/economic/income growth have decelerated.  But either the Fed cannot see or, perhaps like many regulators, it does not feel that righting bubbles is its mandate.  All the same the extremely narrow focus on system dynamics is a disturbing one that has more than likely been a major vitiating factor in the development of current imbalances.

“Investing in social infrastructure as an anti-recession tool”

…is the title of a Washington Centre For Equitable Growth article.  I think that there is some logic to investing in social infrastructure in a slowing growth frame. 

WHY?

In a slowing growth frame less of a corporation’s revenue flows are likely to be reinvested and productive capital is likely to be increasingly depreciated over time, depending on the rate of decline of the frame.  At the moment this cash flow, distributed as either dividends or buybacks, is likely to go disproportionately to those with higher wealth and hence more likely to be reinvested in existing assets, driving up their prices.

In a competitive economic model cash flows would be used to finance the transition to lower growth, with flows consumed and/or used to reduce debt.  As people age the costs associated with complex medical and personal  care needs rise, but these are liabilities that are presently not that well funded.  It makes sense to optimise the allocation of flows to a) fund the economic costs of older adult communities and b) make sure that those at the younger end of the scale continue to receive the necessary education and employment skills training.   This would ensure that the expenditure flows in the economic habitat would be healthier in terms of optimising expenditure and investment.  Imbalances due to inefficient distribution of flows are likely to lead to higher asset price and financial system risks.

In a growth frame where higher levels of productive capital investment is needed it makes sense to have lower corporate tax rates, but in a slower growth frame where higher percentages are distributed it would make sense to tax these distributions at higher levels for more efficient distribution.   In a competitive efficient market place without asymmetric properties we would be less likely to have the present skewed distribution of income and wealth and associated funding pressures on key aspects of social infrastructure.

US debt/asset dynamics……the bubble the Fed appears not to see

In last week’s “Decision Making at the Federal Reserve” at the International House of New York Janet Yellen said that the US economy had made tremendous progress in recovering from the damage caused by the financial crisis, that labour markets were healing and that the economy was on a solid course.  She also said the economy was not a bubble economy, and that if you were to look for evidence of financial instability brewing you would not find it in key areas: over valued asset prices, high leverage and rapid credit growth.  She and the FRB did not see those imbalances and despite weak growth would not describe what we currently see in the US as a bubble economy.

Perhaps the question was the wrong one.   The bubble, indeed most bubbles, are financial in nature and relate to both the flow of financing and the current stock of financing.   We are always in a bubble to some extent given that one of the key facets of the monetary system is the discounting of the present value of future flows through the allocation of assets, principally of money relative to all other assets.  Today’s differential between what the economy can produce over time and the value and supply of assets that represent the future expenditure flows from our economy, are I believe, in excess of the present value of those flows.  Part of this is due to monetary stimulus designed to drive growth forward in the face of demographic change, increasing income inequality (which weakens the expenditure base of the economy) and important transitions in key emerging economies that have numerous structural relationships.

We are in a bubble and while the economic issue today is one of a deflating frame (i.e. not one with inflationary characteristic usually associated with economic overheating), the differential between the financial frame and the economic has arguably never been so wide.  Perhaps the Federal Reserve should have defined what they believed to be a bubble or rather the moderator should have been a bit cleverer! 

Some may say that excess financial leverage of households has moved back to more sensible levels:  the following chart shows that consumer debt levels have moved back to early 2004 levels but that these levels were associated with much higher longer term real GDp growth rates.  In this context debt has not really fully adjusted.

image

And, looking at shorter term real growth trends we see that real GDP growth has peaked at much lower levels relative not just to total debt to the rate of increase in consumer debt.  One would be forgiven for thinking that the last 5 years included a recession in the data, but it has not:

Continue reading